Eighteenth century Scottish economist, author of The Wealth of Nations
See also: FreedomPedia
Adam Smith (c. 16 June 1723 N.S. (c. 5 June 1723 O.S.) – 17 July 1790) was a Scottish economist, philosopher and author as well a moral philosopher, a pioneer of political economy and a key figure during the Scottish Enlightenment era. Smith is best known for two classic works: An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (1776) and The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759). The former, usually abbreviated as The Wealth of Nations, is considered his magnum opus and the first modern work of economics.
Related Groups
Reference
Smith, Adam (1723-1790), by Ronald Hamowy, The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism, 15 Aug 2008
Biographical and bibliographical essay focusing on Adam Smith's two major works
Biographical and bibliographical essay focusing on Adam Smith's two major works
Both a philosopher and political economist, Adam Smith was one of the principal thinkers of 18th-century Scotland, whose name is intimately associated with the early history of economic science ... During his tenure at Glasgow, Smith published his first work, A Theory of Moral Sentiments ... in 1759 ... In 1773, he moved to London, where he completed his monograph on the production and distribution of wealth for which he is now famous. On March 9, 1776, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations was published in two volumes by William Strahan and Thomas Cadell.
Images
TheAdvocates.org - Adam Smith
200x254 JPEG, grayscale
200x254 JPEG, grayscale
Biography
Adam Smith (1723-1790), The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics
Includes list of selected works with links to those hosted by the Library of Economics and Liberty
Includes list of selected works with links to those hosted by the Library of Economics and Liberty
With The Wealth of Nations Adam Smith installed himself as the leading expositor of economic thought. Currents of Adam Smith run through the works published by David Ricardo and Karl Marx in the nineteenth century, and by John Maynard Keynes and Milton Friedman in the twentieth. ... Today Smith's reputation rests on his explanation of how rational self-interest in a free-market economy leads to economic well-being. It may surprise those who would discount Smith as an advocate of ruthless individualism that his first major work concentrates on ethics and charity.
Laissez Faire Books
Very few authors have done as much as the shy Scotsman Smith (1723-1790) to show that society does fine when people are free. While Smith didn't originate many ideas, his big book The Wealth of Nations (1776) was the most impressive and influential presentation. He critiqued Britain's colonial empire and its system of trade restrictions known as mercantilism. He explained how society prospers when private individuals peacefully pursue their self-interest.
Web Pages
Adam Smith | Libertarianism.org
Short profile and links to essays, videos and other resources about Adam Smith
Short profile and links to essays, videos and other resources about Adam Smith
Adam Smith was a Scottish political philosopher and economist, considered one of the forefathers of classical economics and a pioneer of the study of political economy. Smith graduated from Balliol College at Oxford, and later served as the chair of moral philosophy at the University of Glasgow. He departed from his academic position after 12 years to tutor the Duke of Bucchleuch in Switzerland. His two major works, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, and The Theory of Moral Sentiments, were composed after he left the service of the Duke on a lifetime pension.
Adam Smith - Online Library of Liberty
Includes picture, short biography, links to essays about Smith, a timeline of his life and works, several of his writings, including The Weath of Nations and The Theory of Moral Sentiments, and related quotations
Includes picture, short biography, links to essays about Smith, a timeline of his life and works, several of his writings, including The Weath of Nations and The Theory of Moral Sentiments, and related quotations
Adam Smith (1723-1790) is commonly regarded as the first modern economist with the publication in 1776 of The Wealth of Nations. He wrote in a wide range of disciplines: moral philosophy, jurisprudence, rhetoric and literature, and the history of science. ... He is viewed as the founder of modern economic thought, and his work inspires economists to this day. The economic phrase for which he is most famous, the 'invisible hand' of economic incentives, was only one of his many contributions to the modern-day teaching of economics.
Advocates for Self-Government - Libertarian Education: Adam Smith - Libertarian
Biography (from Laissez Faire Books) and picture (of statue of Smith)
Biography (from Laissez Faire Books) and picture (of statue of Smith)
Smith has inspired friends of liberty around the world for more than 200 years. Smith's book The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759) explored human motivations other than self-interest. He delivered thoughtful lectures on jurisprudence. He corresponded with the leading thinkers of his day. Adam Smith offers readers much wisdom and pleasure.
Articles
Adam Smith and the Invisible Hand, by Edmund A. Opitz, The Freeman, Jun 1976
Explains mercantilism, the rationales for political power, government's proper role, Smith's "invisible hand" metaphor, his concept of "equality, liberty and justice" and how a free society allocates economic goods; from a lecture given 17 Feb 1976
Explains mercantilism, the rationales for political power, government's proper role, Smith's "invisible hand" metaphor, his concept of "equality, liberty and justice" and how a free society allocates economic goods; from a lecture given 17 Feb 1976
Smith had made a name for himself with an earlier volume entitled Theory of the Moral Sentiments, published in 1759, but he is now remembered mainly for his Wealth of Nations, on which he labored for ten years ... Adam Smith liked this metaphor of "an invisible hand" and used it in Theory of the Moral Sentiments as well as in The Wealth of Nations ... The Wealth of Nations is generally regarded as a work on economics, but Smith did not think of himself as an economist. Smith was a professor of Moral Philosophy at the University of Glasgow, where he lectured on ethics, rhetoric, jurisprudence, and political economy.
Adam Smith - Hero of the Day, The Daily Objectivist, 2000
Biographical profile published by The Daily Objectivist
Biographical profile published by The Daily Objectivist
Adam Smith, a major figure of the Scottish Enlightenment, was a self-taught professor of moral philosophy at the University of Glasgow. His work on a theory of 'moral sentiments' preceded and informed his far more influential thinking on economics. Smith argued that the most productive social system is one in which, with few exceptions, individuals are free to pursue their economic interest.
Adam Smith—"I had almost forgot that I was the author of the inquiry concerning The Wealth of Nations", by Jim Powell, The Freeman, Mar 1995
Biographical essay
Biographical essay
Before Adam Smith, it seemed that most people believed government was necessary to make an economy work ... Adam Smith defied all this with The Wealth of Nations, a clarion call for economic liberty. Although many specifics weren't original with Smith, he created a bold vision which inspired people everywhere. He showed that the way to achieve peace and prosperity is to set individuals free. He attacked one type of government intervention after another. He recommended liberating Britain's American colonies. He denounced slavery. Smith had an enormous impact on ideas, where change begins.
Adam Smith Needs a Paper Clip: The pin factory, re-examined, by Virginia Postrel, Reason, May 2017
A short history of pins as fasteners from Adam Smith in the late 18th century to the invention of the paper clip at the turn of the 19th century
A short history of pins as fasteners from Adam Smith in the late 18th century to the invention of the paper clip at the turn of the 19th century
Adam Smith famously used a pin factory to illustrate the advantages of specialization, choosing this "very trifling manufacture" because the different tasks were performed under one roof ... By improving workers' skills and encouraging purpose-built machinery, the division of labor leads to miraculous productivity gains. Even a small and ill-equipped manufacturer, Smith wrote in The Wealth of Nations, could boost each worker's output from a handful of pins a day to nearly 5,000 ... In Smith's time and for a century after, pins were a multipurpose fastening technology.
Related Topics: Free trade, The Wealth of Nations
The Ambitious, Accommodative Adam Smith [PDF], by Salim Rashid, The Independent Review, 1997
Criticizes Adam Smith mostly based on his purported behavior, as evidenced in some of his personal writings and reports of some of his biographers, with minimal discussion of his economics or philosophical writings
Criticizes Adam Smith mostly based on his purported behavior, as evidenced in some of his personal writings and reports of some of his biographers, with minimal discussion of his economics or philosophical writings
The approach adopted in The Wealth of Nations attracts many readers because of its close link with natural-rights arguments and political radicalism. ... Many have noted Smith's sympathy for laborers and farm workers and his hostility toward masters and landlords. Combined with the general emphasis on liberty—recall the radical stress on liberty of his old teacher, Francis Hutcheson—the ideas would appear to have been a powerful solvent of traditional ideas, especially in Europe ...
Anne Robert Jacques Turgot, Who First Put Laissez-Faire Principles into Action, by Jim Powell, The Freeman, Aug 1997
Biographical essay, covering his life, works and involvement with the Physiocrats, as well as his accomplishments as an administrator
Biographical essay, covering his life, works and involvement with the Physiocrats, as well as his accomplishments as an administrator
Referring to Turgot, Adam Smith wrote that "I had the happiness of his acquaintance, and, I flattered myself, even of his friendship and esteem." ... Turgot was in touch with others who embraced ideas of liberty. He dined with the Scottish moral philosopher Adam Smith when he visited Paris in 1765, and later Turgot helped supply Smith with books for his work on The Wealth of Nations. But as intellectual historian Peter Groenewegen has shown, Turgot had little impact on Smith's writing, since Smith had already formed his principal views ... [B]oth men believed in economic liberty ...
Areopagitica: Milton's Influence on Classical and Modern Political and Economic Thought, by Isaac M. Morehouse, 15 Dec 2009
Discusses the four sections of Milton's 1644 pamphlet, the reasons for which and the environment in which it was published, and various lessons or parallels that can be made from an economic and political philosophy perspective
Discusses the four sections of Milton's 1644 pamphlet, the reasons for which and the environment in which it was published, and various lessons or parallels that can be made from an economic and political philosophy perspective
In his defense of free speech on moral grounds, we see in Milton much that would later be picked up by Adam Smith, both in his Theory of Moral Sentiments and The Wealth of Nations. Of note is the notion that human vice cannot be done away with by imperial edict, but that a system must be allowed which manages, reduces, and channels vice to the best ends. For both Milton and Smith, that system required freedom from government interference. In one of Smith's most famous passages he says that under free-market competition, each person in their self-interest is guided, "as if by an invisible hand" to do good for society.
Barack Obama: The Anti Economic Growth President, by Jim Powell, 29 Feb 2012
Lists and criticizes several of Obama's policies and proposals and discusses why economic growth and progress is beneficial
Lists and criticizes several of Obama's policies and proposals and discusses why economic growth and progress is beneficial
A key breakthrough in economic understanding came when the shy Scotsman Adam Smith wrote An Inquiry Into The Nature And Causes Of The Wealth Of Nations (1776). ... Smith's most famous lines: '[a typical investor] intends only his own security; and by directing that industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention. By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it.'
Cantillon for Laymen, by Karen De Coster, Mises Daily, 7 Jun 2006
Discusses in general terms the themes in Richard Cantillon's Essai sur la nature du commerce en général (1755), including a short biographical section
Discusses in general terms the themes in Richard Cantillon's Essai sur la nature du commerce en général (1755), including a short biographical section
This ... and has led many scholars, to label [Cantillon] — not Adam Smith — the father of modern economics (Thornton 1999, pp. 13-15) ... Cantillon's groundbreaking tract was of great importance for several reasons, the central reason being that he explained the economy as dynamic and unified, wherein entrepreneurs made profit in the pursuit of self-interest, what Adam Smith later termed "the invisible hand." ... One notable aspect of Cantillon's work is that he is quoted in Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations, and citing others is something that Smith rarely did (Thornton 2001, p. 14).
Related Topics: Richard Cantillon, Entrepreneurs, F. A. Hayek, Israel Kirzner, François Quesnay, Murray N. Rothbard
Classical Liberalism in Argentina: A Lesson for the World, by Jacob G. Hornberger, Freedom Daily, Jul 1994
Highlights Argentine history from the 1810 revolution to the late 20th century, arguing that the period from 1852 to 1930 demonstrated the validity of Adam Smith's writings, also discussing 1958 visits by Leonard Read and Ludwig von Mises
Highlights Argentine history from the 1810 revolution to the late 20th century, arguing that the period from 1852 to 1930 demonstrated the validity of Adam Smith's writings, also discussing 1958 visits by Leonard Read and Ludwig von Mises
Two centuries ago, Adam Smith asked a very fundamental question: what are the nature and causes of the wealth of nations? Note that Smith did not ask what most people today ask—that is, what are the causes of poverty? Smith understood that poverty had always been the natural state of mankind. He wanted to know something much more vital—what is it that causes certain nations to be wealthy and prosperous? ... Smith concluded that throughout history, it had been governments' attempts to defeat poverty that had prevented nations from becoming wealthy and prosperous.
Related Topics: Argentina, Atlas Network, Founding Fathers, Ludwig von Mises, Leonard Read, The Wealth of Nations
David Hume and the Theory of Money, by Murray N. Rothbard, Economic Thought Before Adam Smith, 1995
Excerpted from section 15.4; brief overview and criticism of Hume's philosophical views followed by discussion of his monetary theory contrasting it with the thoughts of Cantillon, Turgot and Austrian school economists
Excerpted from section 15.4; brief overview and criticism of Hume's philosophical views followed by discussion of his monetary theory contrasting it with the thoughts of Cantillon, Turgot and Austrian school economists
David Hume (1711–76), the famous Scottish philosopher, was a close friend of Adam Smith's who was named Smith's executor ... Turning to the other areas of economics, it is possible that some of the deep flaws in Adam Smith's value theory were the result of David Hume's influence. For Hume had no systematic theory of value, and had no idea whatever of utility as a determinant of value. If anything, he kept stressing that labor was the source of all value.
Economic Ideas: Francis Hutcheson and a System of Natural Liberty, by Richard Ebeling, William Holden, 21 Nov 2016
Discusses the main themes in Hutcheson's System of Moral Philosophy
Discusses the main themes in Hutcheson's System of Moral Philosophy
Adam Smith was one of Hutcheson’s students in Glasgow, and his influence on Adam Smith was singularly significant, from everything from the importance of division of labor and the role of private property, to the normative notion of a free society based on a "system of natural liberty." ... this was, in essence, a central message in Francis Hutcheson's own political and economic philosophy. And it was the starting point for Adam Smith's own profound contributions a few decades later, after his time studying with Hutcheson at the University of Glasgow.
Francis Hutcheson: teacher of Adam Smith, by Murray N. Rothbard, Economic Thought Before Adam Smith, 1995
Section 15.2: discusses Hutcheson's life, the main economic themes in his writings and his criticism of Mandeville
Section 15.2: discusses Hutcheson's life, the main economic themes in his writings and his criticism of Mandeville
The 'never-to-be-forgotten Dr. Hutcheson,' as Adam Smith referred to him in a letter half a century later, was the first Glasgow professor to teach in English instead of Latin ... His lectures ... drew students from all over Britain, the most famous of whom was Adam Smith, who studied under him from 1737 to 1740 ... The specific influences of Hutcheson on Adam Smith will be detailed further below; suffice it to say here that the order of topics of Hutcheson's lectures ... as heard by young Smith at the University of Glasgow, is almost the same as the order of chapters in the Wealth of Nations.
Frank A. Fetter: A Forgotten Giant, by Jeffrey Herbener, 16 Aug 2000
Biographical and bibliographical essay
Biographical and bibliographical essay
Fetter also recognized the larger significance of a subjective value theory replacing an objective one in the history of economic thought. He said that, "the labor theory of value had been adopted by Adam Smith after only the most superficial discussion" which led him to "his confusion of ideas regarding labor embodied and labor commanded, labor as the source and as the measure of value, rent and profits now forming a part and now not a part of price." Fetter concluded, that "the resulting confusion was felt by all of the next generation of economists."
Related Topics: Austrian Economics, Entrepreneurship, Frank Fetter, Henry George, Money, David Ricardo
Frederic Bastiat, Ingenious Champion for Liberty and Peace, by Jim Powell, The Freeman, Jun 1997
Biographical essay of Frédéric Bastiat, covering those who influenced him as well as those influenced by him, his writings (including correspondence with his friend Coudroy), his roles in the French Constituent and Legistative Assemblies and his legacy
Biographical essay of Frédéric Bastiat, covering those who influenced him as well as those influenced by him, his writings (including correspondence with his friend Coudroy), his roles in the French Constituent and Legistative Assemblies and his legacy
[Jean Baptiste Say] worked for a while in Britain before joining a Paris insurance company. There his boss suggested that he read Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations. The book thrilled him, and he resolved to learn more about how an economy works ... Say discarded Smith's labor theory of value, insisting that value was determined by customers.
Free Trade, by Alan S. Blinder, The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics, 2008
Presents the case for free trade by pointing out various protectionist arguments which are mistaken or fall short of their presumed benefits
Presents the case for free trade by pointing out various protectionist arguments which are mistaken or fall short of their presumed benefits
We understand intuitively that cutting ourselves off from specialists can only lower our standard of living. Adam Smith's insight was that precisely the same logic applies to nations. Here is how he put it in 1776:
It is the maxim of every prudent master of a family, never to attempt to make at home what it will cost him more to make than to buy ... If a foreign country can supply us with a commodity cheaper than we ourselves can make it, better buy it of them with some part of the produce of our own industry, employed in a way in which we have some advantage.
Full Context, by Sheldon Richman, The Freeman, Apr 2006
Explains why, when arguing against government interventions, such as an oil windfall-profits tax or labor market regulations, it is essential to be aware that the existing corporatist economy does not equate to the free market
Explains why, when arguing against government interventions, such as an oil windfall-profits tax or labor market regulations, it is essential to be aware that the existing corporatist economy does not equate to the free market
In The Wealth of Nations Adam Smith famously wrote, "People of the same trade seldom meet together, even for merriment and diversion, but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against the publick, or in some contrivance to raise prices." It may seem strange that history's best-known advocate of the free market would cast such aspersions ... Opponents of the free market love that quote [but] they rarely add the sentences that follow: "It is impossible indeed to prevent such meetings, by any law which either could be executed, or would be consistent with liberty and justice ..."
Related Topics: Corporatism, Free Market
Hayek and the Scots on Liberty [PDF], by Gerald P. O'Driscoll, Jr., The Journal of Private Enterprise, 2015
Explores the influence of the eighteenth-century Scottish moral philosophers, mainly David Hume and Adam Smith, on Hayek's thinking about liberty and concepts such as natural law theory
Explores the influence of the eighteenth-century Scottish moral philosophers, mainly David Hume and Adam Smith, on Hayek's thinking about liberty and concepts such as natural law theory
Why did Hayek not rely more on Adam Smith? Hayek (1976a) provided an answer in a short essay, 'Adam Smith's Message in Today's Language.' He tells us that in forty years of lecturing, he always found the lectures on Smith 'particularly difficult to give.' ... Ebenstein ... tells us that Hayek's 'appreciation for Smith rose over his lifetime.' ... That assessment is supported by Hayek's characterization of Smith's contribution to the emergence of liberalism in the essay of that name. 'Adam Smith's decisive contribution was the account of a self-generating order which formed itself spontaneously if the individuals were restrained by appropriate rules of law'.
Home Study Course: Module 4: Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations (Part I)
Fourth module of the Cato Home Study Course, includes link to listen or download audio program (2:33:34), questions and suggested readings
Fourth module of the Cato Home Study Course, includes link to listen or download audio program (2:33:34), questions and suggested readings
Adam Smith (1723-90) was not the first to try to understand the market economy, but he may have been the most influential and eloquent observer of economic life. His observation that a person may be "led by an invisible hand to promote an end that was no part of his intention" became the guiding star of an investigation of the beneficial unintended consequences of voluntary exchange, an investigation that still continues strong after more than two hundred years.
Related Topics: Free Market, Netherlands
The Inherently Humble Libertarian, by Sheldon Richman, The Goal Is Freedom, 13 Feb 2015
Defends libertarianism from those who charge its advocates of "know-it-allness"
Defends libertarianism from those who charge its advocates of "know-it-allness"
That ... is an allusion to Adam Smith's insight about the "man of system" in The Theory of Moral Sentiments:
The man of system ... is often so enamoured with the supposed beauty of his own ideal plan of government, that he cannot suffer the smallest deviation from any part of it. He goes on to establish it completely and in all its parts, without any regard either to the great interests, or to the strong prejudices which may oppose it. He seems to imagine that he can arrange the different members of a great society with as much ease as the hand arranges the different pieces upon a chess-board ...
Related Topics: Milton Friedman, Libertarianism
The Invisible Hand Is a Gentle Hand, by Sharon Harris, 14 Sep 1998
Originally published at HarryBrowne.org; defends the free market and individual liberty, quoting among others Bastiat, Thomas Jefferson, David and Milton Friedman, John Lott, Isabel Paterson, Proudhon, Adam Smith, Sowell, John Stossel and Walter Williams
Originally published at HarryBrowne.org; defends the free market and individual liberty, quoting among others Bastiat, Thomas Jefferson, David and Milton Friedman, John Lott, Isabel Paterson, Proudhon, Adam Smith, Sowell, John Stossel and Walter Williams
It's time to speak out for the free market and individual liberty. The great economist Adam Smith wrote that a free society operates as if "an invisible hand" directs people's actions—in such a way as to serve the interest of the whole society. That invisible hand is a gentle one ... The gentle invisible hand vs. the visible fist of government. Adam Smith said It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer or the baker that we expect our dinner, but from their regard for their own interest." In the marketplace, people tend to be well mannered—even if they hate you.
Jean-Baptiste Say: Neglected Champion of Laissez-Faire, by Larry J. Sechrest, 15 Jul 2000
Biographical and bibliographical essay, discussing Say's life, methodology and his writings on money, banking, the law of markets, entrepreneurship, capital, interest, value, utility, taxes and the state
Biographical and bibliographical essay, discussing Say's life, methodology and his writings on money, banking, the law of markets, entrepreneurship, capital, interest, value, utility, taxes and the state
Say did explicitly represent his work as being mainly an elaboration and popularization of Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations for the benefit of continental European readers ... [A]lthough Say frequently praises Smith, he also departs from Smithian doctrine on a number of important points. In fact, Say even sharply criticizes Adam Smith on more than one occasion ... [T]hese two men represent two meandering, but generally divergent, paths embedded within classical economics. Smith leads one to David Ricardo, John Stuart Mill, Alfred Marshall, Irving Fisher, John Maynard Keynes, and Milton Friedman.
Related Topics: Banking, Economics, Austrian Economics, Entrepreneurship, Free Market, Money, Prices, Jean-Baptiste Say, Taxation
Letters to Mr. Malthus, on Several Subjects of Political Economy, and on the Cause of the Stagnation of Commerce, by Jean-Baptiste Say, 1820
Original title: Lettres à M. Malthus, sur différens sujets d'économie politique, notamment sur les causes de la stagnation générale du commerce
Series of five letters from Say to Malthus, written in response to the latter's criticisms in Principles of Political Economy (1820); the letters were translated from the French by John Richter
Original title: Lettres à M. Malthus, sur différens sujets d'économie politique, notamment sur les causes de la stagnation générale du commerce
Series of five letters from Say to Malthus, written in response to the latter's criticisms in Principles of Political Economy (1820); the letters were translated from the French by John Richter
Instead of weakening the authority of the celebrated Inquiry into the Wealth of Nations, I support it in the most essential part; but ... I think Adam Smith has forgotten some real exchangeable values, in omitting those which are attached to such productive services as leave no trace because they are totally consumed ... I revere Adam Smith—he is my master. When I took the first steps in political economy ... I stumbled at every move—he shewed me the true path. Supported by his Wealth of Nations, which shews at the same time his own intellectual wealth, I learned to go alone.
Related Topics: Capital Goods, Capitalism, Economics, Entrepreneurship, Europe, Farming, Free trade, Government, Labor, Prices, Taxation, Technology, United States
Liberalism, by F. A. Hayek, New Studies in Philosophy, Politics, Economics and the History of Ideas, 1978
Chapter 9; originally written in 1973 for the Enciclopedia del Novicento; covers both the history of both strands of liberalism as well as a systematic description of the "classical" or "evolutionary" type
Chapter 9; originally written in 1973 for the Enciclopedia del Novicento; covers both the history of both strands of liberalism as well as a systematic description of the "classical" or "evolutionary" type
Adam Smith's decisive contribution was the account of a self-generating order which formed itself spontaneously if the individuals were restrained by appropriate rules of law. His Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations marks perhaps more than any other single work the beginning of the development of modern liberalism. It made people understand that those restrictions on the powers of government which had originated from sheer distrust of all arbitrary power had become the chief cause of Britain's economic prosperity.
Related Topics: United States Bill of Rights, Democracy, David Hume, Inflation, Law, Individual Liberty, John Locke, John Stuart Mill, Herbert Spencer, United States
Libertarianism Is Not Atheist, Is Not Religious, by Wendy McElroy, The Daily Bell, 9 Oct 2014
Examines Rothbard's views in a 1987 article about freedom and religion, in particular regarding Ayn Rand's atheistic influences on early modern libertarianism
Examines Rothbard's views in a 1987 article about freedom and religion, in particular regarding Ayn Rand's atheistic influences on early modern libertarianism
Adam Smith formulated well the distinction between political duty and morality. Each person had a political duty to not aggress against anyone else. For restraining his actions, however, no person deserved praise. He was simply performing his duty. Morality lay in the benevolent actions taken over and above the call of duty–in acts of kindness or charity, in comforting the afflicted or providing compassion. For such acts, a person deserved praise for being a moral human being.
Libertarianism: The Moral and the Practical, by Sheldon Richman, Future of Freedom, May 2014
Explores whether libertarian policies should distinguish between moral and practical concerns; revised version of "The Goal Is Freedom" column of 27 Dec 2013
Explores whether libertarian policies should distinguish between moral and practical concerns; revised version of "The Goal Is Freedom" column of 27 Dec 2013
I'm hardly alone in my uneasiness with this separation of concerns into the moral and the practical. In my camp is no less a personage than Adam Smith. Look at this passage from The Wealth of Nations:
[The] happiness and perfection of a man, considered not only as an individual, but as the member of a family, of a state, and of the great society of mankind, was the object which the ancient moral philosophy proposed to investigate ...... Smith's reference to "ancient philosophy" is a reference to Socrates, Plato, and Aristotle (and perhaps the Thomists whom they inspired) ...
Related Topics: Aristotle, Ethics, Henry Hazlitt, Libertarianism, Roderick T. Long, Tibor Machan, The Wealth of Nations
Module 5: Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations (Part II)
Fifth module of the Cato Home Study Course, includes link to listen or download audio program (2:34:19), questions and suggested readings
Fifth module of the Cato Home Study Course, includes link to listen or download audio program (2:34:19), questions and suggested readings
Adam Smith was both moral philosopher and social scientist. He sought to understand the wellsprings of morality as well as the regulating principles of social life. In seeking to understand the natural laws governing the regularities of economic life, Smith took the time to observe carefully how business enterprises operated, how markets were organized, and how the prices at which goods were exchanged were determined. Working out the relationships of "supply and demand" that determine prices in the market was one of his principal concerns.
Related Topic: Capitalism
Monetary Central Planning and the State, Part 30: The Gold Standard as Government-Managed Money, by Richard M. Ebeling, Freedom Daily, Jun 1999
Describes how, by allowing central banks to manage gold-backed currencies, the road was paved for central planning in other areas
Describes how, by allowing central banks to manage gold-backed currencies, the road was paved for central planning in other areas
In the 19th century there was ... a general agreement [among those who constructed and implemented government economic policies] with Adam Smith's observation that "the statesman, who should attempt to direct private people in what manner they ought to employ their capitals, would not only load himself with a most unnecessary attention, but assume an authority which could safely be trusted, not only to no single person, but to no council or senate, and which would nowhere be so dangerous as in the hands of a man who had the folly and presumption enough to fancy himself fit to exercise it."
Monopoly and Aggression, by Sheldon Richman, The Goal Is Freedom, 19 Dec 2014
Argues that monopoly and aggression are intimately related and that intellectual property laws are currently the main monopolistic interventions
Argues that monopoly and aggression are intimately related and that intellectual property laws are currently the main monopolistic interventions
Adam Smith's approach to monopoly makes more sense than the mainstream neoclassical view. To Smith, monopoly denoted a privilege, a legal barrier to competition, such as a license or a franchise — in other words, a grant from the state. Anyone who attempted to compete with the monopolist would run afoul of the law and be suppressed by force, because that's how the state assures its decrees are faithfully carried out. When someone whose actions are consonant with natural rights is suppressed by force, that is aggression.
Related Topics: Frédéric Bastiat, Intellectual Property Laws, Ludwig von Mises, Monopoly, Murray N. Rothbard
Monopoly, Competition, and Educational Freedom, by Jacob G. Hornberger, Mar 2000
Discusses monopolies and competition in the religious, postal delivery and educational realms and criticizes a speech by Gary Becker about competition in religion and education
Discusses monopolies and competition in the religious, postal delivery and educational realms and criticizes a speech by Gary Becker about competition in religion and education
Monopolies characterized the Age of Mercantilism in the 18th century. Over time, consumers came to hate monopolies, because monopolists, knowing that there was no threat of competition, were customarily arrogant and, more often than not, provided a shoddy product. With the publication of Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations in 1776, people began seriously considering an alternative—the free market. Smith planted the seed that ultimately erupted into the Industrial Revolution. Monopoly privileges were repealed, and people were free to compete in the supplying of goods and services.
Related Topics: Gary Becker, Educational Freedom, Compulsory Education, Government, Occupational Licensing, Monopoly, Freedom of Religion, Taxation
Murray Rothbard Confronts Adam Smith, by Paul B. Trescott, The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 1998
Critical review of Rothbard's chapter about Adam Smith in Economic Thought Before Adam Smith: An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought, Volume I, including both positive and unfavorable points missed by Rothbard
Critical review of Rothbard's chapter about Adam Smith in Economic Thought Before Adam Smith: An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought, Volume I, including both positive and unfavorable points missed by Rothbard
Rothbard cites Schumpeter as one of the first to mount an authoritative deflation of Smith's exaggerated reputation. But Schumpeter also said that The Wealth of Nations "is a great performance all the same and fully deserved its success" ... Rothbard's treatment of Smith's is unfair and inaccurate. His treatment of Cantillon is distorted in the opposite direction. Ironically, many of Rothbard's specific criticisms of Smith would also apply to Cantillon and Turgot.
Related Topic: Murray N. Rothbard
Murray Rothbard's Adam Smith, by Spencer J. Pack, The Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics, 1998
Supportive review of Rothbard's criticisms of Adam Smith in An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought
Supportive review of Rothbard's criticisms of Adam Smith in An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought
Again, largely following Hume, Smith basically did not utilize a natural-law or natural-rights framework. His book on The Theory of Moral Sentiments was an elaborate argument for why humans can get along in society and why they do indeed have morals, wrapped around his theory of 'sympathy.' Although a case can be made that Smith's theory of justice was partly grounded in a natural-law position ... Smith for the most part never used natural-rights and natural-law theory.
Related Topic: Murray N. Rothbard
National Servitude, by Sheldon Richman, The Goal Is Freedom, 21 Jun 2013
Discusses calls for "national service", contrasts them to insights from Frédéric Bastiat and Adam Smith, and counters possible objections
Discusses calls for "national service", contrasts them to insights from Frédéric Bastiat and Adam Smith, and counters possible objections
Adam Smith had more than a few insights into the services that human beings render one another ... [H]e wrote,
In civilized society [the individual] stands at all times in need of the co-operation and assistance of great multitudes, while his whole life is scarce sufficient to gain the friendship of a few persons ... [M]an has almost constant occasion for the help of his brethren, and it is in vain for him to expect it from their benevolence only ...Smith added later that a person's direct efforts to advance the social good are often less effective than efforts motivated by personal gain ...
Non-Marxist Theories of Imperialism, by Alan Fairgate, Reason, Feb 1976
Examines writings of critics of imperialism that are not based on Marxist analysis
Examines writings of critics of imperialism that are not based on Marxist analysis
While early critiques of England's colonial foreign policy had focused primarily on political and moral objections, Adam Smith's Wealth of Nations presented the first comprehensive economic refutation of the mercantilist doctrines which had been used to justify the acquisition of colonies. Upholding the virtues of division of labor, economic specialization, and freedom of trade, Smith persuasively argued that protectionism and regulation of commerce would hamper, rather than promote, economic growth and welfare.
The Origin of Economic Theory: A Portrait of Richard Cantillon (1680-1734), by Mark Thornton, 3 Aug 2007
Examines the sections of Cantillon's Essai relating them to episodes in the author's life, then delving into several Austrian economics insights that can be found in the work
Examines the sections of Cantillon's Essai relating them to episodes in the author's life, then delving into several Austrian economics insights that can be found in the work
The Essai is considered influential for the development of both the Physiocrats and the classical economists, and Cantillon was one of the very few people mentioned by Adam Smith in the Wealth of Nations. Unfortunately, Smith misrepresented Cantillon's work. Both Cantillon and his Essai were largely forgotten during the period of classical economics ... Most importantly, the Scottish philosopher and tax collector Adam Smith should no longer be considered the father of economics. That title now belongs to the Irish entrepreneur and Austrian economist, Richard Cantillon.
Related Topics: Richard Cantillon, Central Banking, Economics, Austrian Economics, Entrepreneurship, Money, Prices
Peace and Pacifism, by Robert Higgs, The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism, 15 Aug 2008
Reviews what prominent classical liberals and libertarians had to say on the subject of peace and war, as well as the history of United States wars from the War of 1812 to the 2003 invasion of Iraq and the efforts of those who opposed them
Reviews what prominent classical liberals and libertarians had to say on the subject of peace and war, as well as the history of United States wars from the War of 1812 to the 2003 invasion of Iraq and the efforts of those who opposed them
Preeminent classical liberals, such as Adam Smith, Richard Cobden, John Bright, William Graham Sumner, and Ludwig von Mises, condemned war as fatal to economic and social progress. Smith famously taught that "little else is requisite to carry a [society] to the highest degree of opulence from the lowest barbarism but peace, easy taxes, and a tolerable administration of justice: all the rest being brought about by the natural course of things."
Physiocracy, by George H. Smith, The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism, 15 Aug 2008
Discusses the Physiocrats, focusing mostly on Quesnay and his Tableau Économique
Discusses the Physiocrats, focusing mostly on Quesnay and his Tableau Économique
Adam Smith writes in the Wealth of Nations that the physiocratic notion of a "barren or unproductive class" was an attempt to "degrade" merchants, manufacturers, and other nonagricultural workers with a "humiliating appellation." Some commentators disagree with Smith's assessment. They maintain that Quesnay and his disciples worked from a purely physical conception of productivity, and that in using the word sterile they did not mean to deny that members of this class provided goods and services that possessed economic utility.
The Physiocrats, by Wendy McElroy, Freedom Daily, Dec 2010
Discusses the 18th century French economists and their influences on Adam Smith, on American agriarianism and on Henry George
Discusses the 18th century French economists and their influences on Adam Smith, on American agriarianism and on Henry George
In the mid 1760s, professor of moral philosophy Adam Smith toured Europe at the behest of the wealthy Duke of Buccleuch who greatly admired Smith's recently published Theory of Moral Sentiments. It was during that period that Smith met Quesnay and commenced writing The Wealth of Nations ... In ... "Of Systems of Political Economy"—Smith details his several disagreements with the Physiocrats and then concludes that "with all its imperfections, [the Physiocratic system] is perhaps the nearest approximation to the truth that has yet been published upon the subject of political economy..."
Related Topics: France, Benjamin Franklin, Henry George, Thomas Jefferson, François Quesnay, Taxation, Anne Robert Jacques Turgot
Reasoning on the Nature of Things, by Clarence B. Carson, The Freeman, Feb 1982
Discusses how natural law doctrines were repudiated by utilitarians, why natural rights are important from an economic viewpoint, how the rights to life, liberty and property can be construed and what the author understands as the "social contract"
Discusses how natural law doctrines were repudiated by utilitarians, why natural rights are important from an economic viewpoint, how the rights to life, liberty and property can be construed and what the author understands as the "social contract"
Smith maintained that the industrious individual in the pursuit of his own interest contributes to the well-being of others when he buys and sells goods in the market. He is bent to the pursuit of his own interest by nature, and his condition in this world is such that if he pursues it in a productive way he must contribute to the general stock of goods. In doing this, "he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases," Smith said, "led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was not part of his intention." There is a natural order of things ... which makes it so.
Related Topics: Jeremy Bentham, Government, Law, Liberty, John Stuart Mill, Philosophy, Property Rights, Ronald Reagan, Rights, Socialism, Society
Self-Interest and Social Order in Classical Liberalism: Bernard Mandeville v. Francis Hutcheson, by George H. Smith, 23 Jan 2015
Discusses the views of Hobbes and Mandeville regarding society and the need for government and the critiques of the latter made by Hutcheson and Adam Smith
Discusses the views of Hobbes and Mandeville regarding society and the need for government and the critiques of the latter made by Hutcheson and Adam Smith
Adam Smith later expressed similar objections in The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Mandeville's approach is 'wholly pernicious' because it 'seems to take away altogether the distinction between vice and virtue.' ... Moreover, contrary to Mandeville, Smith maintained that 'the desire of doing what is honourable and noble, of rendering ourselves the proper objects of esteem and approbation, cannot with any propriety be called vanity. Even the love of well-grounded fame and reputation, the desire of acquiring esteem by what is really estimable, does not deserve that name.'
Related Topics: Francis Hutcheson, Bernard Mandeville
The Spanish-American War: The Leap into Overseas Empire: Part 2, by Joseph R. Stromberg, Freedom Daily, Jan 1999
Discusses the Philippine-American War, that followed the Spanish-American War, and the actions and writings of the Anti-Imperialist League, William Graham Sumner and other opposed to the war and colonialism
Discusses the Philippine-American War, that followed the Spanish-American War, and the actions and writings of the Anti-Imperialist League, William Graham Sumner and other opposed to the war and colonialism
[A]s Adam Smith wrote (oddly enough in 1776):
To found a great empire for the sole purpose of raising up a people of customers, may at first sight appear a project fit only for a nation of shopkeepers. It is, however, a project altogether unfit for a nation of shopkeepers; but extremely fit for a nation whose government is influenced by shopkeepers. Such statesmen, and such statesmen only, are capable of fancying that they will find some advantage in employing the blood and treasure of their fellow citizens, to found and maintain such an empire.
Student at Glasgow College, by John Rae, Life of Adam Smith, 1895
Chapter II of Life of Adam Smith, covering the years 1737 to 1740, and delving mostly on Smith's Moral Philosophy professor, Francis Hutcheson
Chapter II of Life of Adam Smith, covering the years 1737 to 1740, and delving mostly on Smith's Moral Philosophy professor, Francis Hutcheson
... Smith improved his Greek under Dunlop, and acquired a distinct ardour for mathematics under the inspiring instructions of Simson ... He is sometimes considered a disciple of Hume and sometimes ... of Quesnay; if he was any man's disciple, he was Hutcheson's. ... His doctrine was essentially the doctrine of industrial liberty with which Smith's name is identified, and in view of the claims set up on behalf of the French Physiocrats that Smith learnt that doctrine in their school, it is right to remember that he was brought into contact with it in Hutcheson's class-room at Glasgow some twenty years before any of the Physiocrats had written a line on the subject ...
Related Topic: Francis Hutcheson
Tackling Straw Men Is Easier than Critiquing Libertarianism, by Sheldon Richman, 5 Dec 2014
Counters John Edward Terrell's critique of libertarianism (in "Evolution and the American Myth of the Individual") using quotes from Adam Smith, Vernon Smith and Herbert Spencer
Counters John Edward Terrell's critique of libertarianism (in "Evolution and the American Myth of the Individual") using quotes from Adam Smith, Vernon Smith and Herbert Spencer
Has Terrell never heard of [Adam] Smith's The Theory of Moral Sentiments, published in 1859—17 years before The Wealth of Nations and revised throughout his life? Or is he in that group of scribblers who think The Wealth of Nations was all that Smith had to say about the human enterprise? ... For Terrell's edification, I'll point out that The Theory of Moral Sentiments is an extended discussion of "fellow-feeling," that is, our natural sympathy for others. Smith would laugh at any portrayal of the isolated, allegedly self-sufficient individual as the summit of human development.
Why Those Who Value Liberty Should Rejoice: Elinor Ostrom's Nobel Prize, by Peter Boettke, The Freeman, Dec 2009
Discusses Elinor Ostrom's work and viewpoints, shortly after her being awarded the Nobel Prize in economics
Discusses Elinor Ostrom's work and viewpoints, shortly after her being awarded the Nobel Prize in economics
In the history of political and economic thought the source of social order has been attributed either to the invisible hand of market coordination (Adam Smith) or the heavy hand of state control (Hobbes). Perhaps one of the best ways to understand Elinor Ostrom's work is to see it as working out a Hobbesian problem by way of a Smithian solution. That is perhaps a bit of a stretch but not by much.
Work!, by Sheldon Richman, The Goal Is Freedom, 7 Mar 2014
Contrasts the "gospel of work" and "joy of labor" espoused by moralists and state socialists with the views of economists such as Adam Smith, Bastiat, John Stuart Mill, Mises and Rothbard
Contrasts the "gospel of work" and "joy of labor" espoused by moralists and state socialists with the views of economists such as Adam Smith, Bastiat, John Stuart Mill, Mises and Rothbard
Adam Smith and other early economists equated work with "toil," which is not a word overflowing with positive connotations. In The Wealth of Nations, Smith writes, "The real price of every thing, what every thing really costs to the man who wants to acquire it, is the toil and trouble of acquiring it. What every thing is really worth to the man ... is the toil and trouble which it can save to himself, and which it can impose upon other people. What is bought with money or with goods is purchased by labour, as much as what we acquire by the toil of our own body. That money, or those goods, indeed, save us this toil."
The Writings of Adam Smith, by Julio H. Cole, The Freeman, Feb 1990
Biographical essay, including not only the two major works published during Adam Smith's lifetime, but also the lectures and other writing published posthumously
Biographical essay, including not only the two major works published during Adam Smith's lifetime, but also the lectures and other writing published posthumously
Smith took economics forever beyond the narrow mercantilistic framework which denied the gains from trade between nations, and made of it a study of the spontaneous and largely unintended social order which arises from free exchanges between individuals, exchanges which produce benefits for all parties involved, whether domestic or foreign. For as long as the love of liberty survives in this world, free men will continue to derive inspiration from Adam Smith, author of The Wealth of Nations.
Writings
Of the Rent of Land, The Wealth of Nations, 1776
Book One, Chapter XI
Book One, Chapter XI
Rent, considered as the price paid for the use of land, is naturally the highest which the tenant can afford to pay in the actual circumstances of the land. In adjusting the terms of the lease, the landlord endeavours to leave him no greater share of the produce than what is sufficient to keep up the stock from which he furnishes the seed, pays the labour, and purchases and maintains the cattle and other instruments of husbandry, together with the ordinary profits of farming stock in the neighbourhood.
Related Topic: Land
Of the Wages of Labour, The Wealth of Nations, 1776
Book One, Chapter VIII
Book One, Chapter VIII
The produce of labour constitutes the natural recompence or wages of labour. In that original state of things, which precedes both the appropriation of land and the accumulation of stock, the whole produce of labour belongs to the labourer. He has neither landlord nor master to share with him. Had this state continued, the wages of labour would have augmented with all those improvements in its productive powers, to which the division of labour gives occasion. All things would gradually have become cheaper
Related Topic: Wages
Reviews
Economic Thought Before Adam Smith—An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought, Volume 1, by Gregory P. Pavlik, The Freeman, Oct 1995
Review of Murray Rothbard's Economic Thought Before Adam Smith (1995) (note: despite the title, Adam Smith is included in this volume and the review)
Review of Murray Rothbard's Economic Thought Before Adam Smith (1995) (note: despite the title, Adam Smith is included in this volume and the review)
[Rothbard] is almost without exception hostile, deeming [Adam] Smith a proto-Marxist, and, following Schumpeter, an obstacle for the development of sound economic theory. For Rothbard, Smith interjected the labor theory of value into economics and pioneered an extreme variant of the egalitarianism that plagues political dialogue to this day. Contrary to conventional wisdom, Rothbard holds that even Smith's famous "invisible hand" was not original, and that Smith's emphasis on the division of labor neglected the importance of specialization in the economy as a whole.
Book Review: J.-B. Say: An Economist in Troubled Times, by Richard M. Ebeling, Freedom Daily, May 1998
Review of J.-B. Say: An Economist in Troubled Times (1997), writings selected and translated by R. R. Palmer
Review of J.-B. Say: An Economist in Troubled Times (1997), writings selected and translated by R. R. Palmer
In place of mercantilism, [the classical liberals and economists of the first half of the 19th century] advocated Adam Smith's "system of natural liberty," under which government would be limited, mostly, to the protection of life, liberty, and property. Free men pursuing their individual self-interests would peacefully exchange and, as if guided by an "invisible hand," the cumulative result of their transactions would generate a greater "wealth of nations" than when governments consciously attempted to plan the economic activities of their citizens and subjects.
Interviews
Interview with Adam Smith [via Edwin West], by E. G. West, The Region, Jun 1994
Professor Edwin G. West stands in for Adam Smith and answers questions from the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis banking and policy issues magazine, The Region
Professor Edwin G. West stands in for Adam Smith and answers questions from the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis banking and policy issues magazine, The Region
Smith: ... Like other members of the Scottish School I was trying to establish what you now call a comparative systems approach, and you will find in my The Wealth of Nations a wide survey of many forms of societies, including Greek republics, democracies, monarchies, federal governments, governments of mercantile companies, the American colonies and established churches. I was attempting to determine what bearing these institutional differences had upon relative economic success. But what was also new was that such success was measured in terms of per capita, not per monarch, per company ...
Related Topics: Banking, Central Banking, Economic Freedom, Educational Freedom, Hong Kong, India, Japan, John Stuart Mill, Minimum Wage Laws, Russia, Taxation
Books Authored
The Theory of Moral Sentiments, 1759
Partial contents: Of the Propriety of Action Consisting of Three Sections - Of Merit and Demerit; or of the Objects of Reward and Punishment - Of the Foundation of our Judgments concerning our own Sentiments and Conduct, and of the Sense of Duty
Partial contents: Of the Propriety of Action Consisting of Three Sections - Of Merit and Demerit; or of the Objects of Reward and Punishment - Of the Foundation of our Judgments concerning our own Sentiments and Conduct, and of the Sense of Duty
Related Topic: Ethics
- ISBN 0521591503: Hardcover, Cambridge University Press, 2002
- ISBN 0895263637: Hardcover, Regnery Publishing, 1999
- ISBN 0521598478: Paperback, Cambridge University Press, 2002
- ISBN 0865970122: Paperback, Liberty Fund, 1982
- ISBN 1419185071: Paperback, Kessinger Publishing, 2004
- ISBN 1573928003: Paperback, Prometheus Books, 2000
An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
by Adam Smith, Methuen & Co., The Wealth of Nations, 1904
by Adam Smith, Methuen & Co., The Wealth of Nations, 1904
The Wealth of Nations, Mar 1776
Full title: An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
Partial contents: Of the Causes of Improvement in the productive... - Of the Nature, Accumulation, and Employment of Stock - Of the different Progress of Opulence in different Nations - Of Systems of political Œconomy - Of the Revenue of the Sovereign...
Full title: An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
Partial contents: Of the Causes of Improvement in the productive... - Of the Nature, Accumulation, and Employment of Stock - Of the different Progress of Opulence in different Nations - Of Systems of political Œconomy - Of the Revenue of the Sovereign...
Related Topics: Economics, The Wealth of Nations
- ISBN 0679424733: Hardcover, Modern Library, 1994
- ISBN 0895263351: Hardcover, Regnery Publishing, 1999
- ISBN 0192835467: Paperback, Oxford University Press, 1998
- ISBN 0226763749: Paperback, University Of Chicago Press, 1977
- ISBN 0679783369: Paperback, Modern Library, 2000
- ISBN 0865970084: Paperback, Liberty Fund, 2 volumes, 1982
- ISBN 0879757051: Paperback, Prometheus Books, 1991
Videos
Adam Smith: The Invisible Hand, by James Otteson, 29 Aug 2011
Short video, with transcript, with brief explanations of the concepts of the "invisible hand" and the division of labor
Short video, with transcript, with brief explanations of the concepts of the "invisible hand" and the division of labor
Adam Smith was one of the principals of an astonishing period of human learning, called the Scottish Enlightenment, during the 18th century. He's the author of two books. In 1759, The Theory of Moral Sentiments was his first book. In 1776, the one he's more famous for now, An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Those two books together almost singlehandedly began the discipline of political economy.
The Real Adam Smith: Ideas That Changed The World, by Johan Norberg, 26 Mar 2016
Second part of The Real Adam Smith: A Personal Exploration by Johan Norberg, a television documentary produced by Free To Choose Media
The Real Adam Smith: Morality and Markets, by Johan Norberg, 26 Mar 2016
First part of The Real Adam Smith: A Personal Exploration by Johan Norberg, a television documentary produced by Free To Choose Media
Podcasts
Is Adam Smith the Father of Economics and Free-Market Capitalism? [Reason Podcast], by Nick Gillespie, Naomi Brockwell (moderator), Gene Epstein, Mark Skousen, 5 Jul 2017
Report, audio and transcript of the debate, held on 13 Jun 2017, on the resolution "Adam Smith should be honored as the founder of modern economics and free-enterprise capitalism" between Mark Skousen for the affirmative and Gene Epstein for the negative
Report, audio and transcript of the debate, held on 13 Jun 2017, on the resolution "Adam Smith should be honored as the founder of modern economics and free-enterprise capitalism" between Mark Skousen for the affirmative and Gene Epstein for the negative
[Skousen] Adam Smith was a revolutionary. His doctrine revolutionized European society as surely as Marx in a later epic. He was on the economic side as a philosopher of the capitalist revolution. As John Locke was his philosopher on the political side and Newton was the natural philosopher on the physical sciences. ...
[Epstein] Mark would try to have us cover up key parts of Smith's own writings. Smith's book The Wealth of Nations includes a whole range of sustained arguments that were anti free market and even pro socialist, ignoring these arguments by Smith is not only dishonest, it's dangerous.
[Epstein] Mark would try to have us cover up key parts of Smith's own writings. Smith's book The Wealth of Nations includes a whole range of sustained arguments that were anti free market and even pro socialist, ignoring these arguments by Smith is not only dishonest, it's dangerous.
Related Topics: Richard Cantillon, Murray N. Rothbard
The introductory paragraph uses material from the Wikipedia article "Adam Smith" as of 17 Jul 2018, which is released under the Creative Commons Attribution-Share-Alike License 3.0.